|
Notes: Computer I & II |
These notes are not complete and there is no guarantee that they are accurate. They are presented simply as notes. Feel free to use them but as with all material on the Cybertelecom, you should consider them a beginning to your research and not an end.
The Commission has long sought to maintain appropriate safeguards for the provision by the BOCs of enhanced services.[9] Since its Computer I proceeding, the Commission has adopted a variety of regulatory tools to prevent improper cost allocation and access discrimination against ESPs in the provision of enhanced services, both by the BOCs, and, before divestiture, by their predecessor in interest, AT&T.[10] In the Computer II proceeding, the Commission required the then-integrated Bell System to establish structurally separate affiliates for the provision of enhanced services in order to address the concern over AT&T's incentive and ability to engage in anticompetitive activity.[11] Following the divestiture of AT&T in 1984,[12] the Commission extended the structural separation requirements of Computer II to the BOCs.[13] In Computer III, after reexamining the telecommunications marketplace and the effects of structural separation during the six years since Computer II, the Commission determined that the costs of structural separation outweighed the benefits, and that nonstructural safeguards could protect competitive ESPs from improper cost allocation and discrimination by the BOCs while avoiding the inefficiencies associated with structural separation.[14]
[9] Basic services, such as Aplain old telephone service@ (POTS), are regulated as tariffed services under Title II of the Communications Act. Enhanced services use the existing telephone network to deliver services that provide more than a basic transmission offering. Examples of enhanced services include, among other things, voice mail, electronic mail, electronic store-and-forward, facsimile store-and-forward, data processing, and gateways to online databases. See, e.g. Bell Operating Companies' Joint Petition for Waiver of Computer II Rules, Memorandum Opinion and Order, 10 FCC Rcd 1724 n.3 (1995) (Interim Waiver Order); 47 C.F.R. ' 64.702(a); Amendment of Section 64.702 of the Commission's Rules and Regulations (Computer III), Report and Order, CC Docket No. 85-229, Phase I, 104 FCC 2d 958 (1986) (Phase I Order), recon., 2 FCC Rcd 3035 (1987) (Phase I Recon. Order), further recon., 3 FCC Rcd 1135 (1988) (Phase I Further Recon. Order), second further recon., 4 FCC Rcd 5927 (1989) (Phase I Second Further Recon.), Phase I Order and Phase I Recon. Order, vacated, California v. FCC, 905 F.2d 1217 (9th Cir. 1990) (California I); Phase II, 2 FCC Rcd 3072 (1987) (Phase II Order), recon., 3 FCC Rcd 1150 (1988) (Phase II Recon. Order), further recon., 4 FCC Rcd 5927 (1989) (Phase II Further Recon. Order), Phase II Order vacated, California I, 905 F.2d 1217 (9th Cir. 1990); Computer III Remand Proceedings, 5 FCC Rcd 7719 (1990) (ONA Remand Order), recon., 7 FCC Rcd 909 (1992), pets. for review denied, California v. FCC, 4 F.3d 1505 (9th Cir. 1993) (California II); Computer III Remand Proceedings: Bell Operating Company Safeguards and Tier 1 Local Exchange Company Safeguards, 6 FCC Rcd 7571 (1991) (BOC Safeguards Order), recon. dismissed in part, Order, CC Docket Nos. 90-623, 11 FCC Rcd 12513 (1996); BOC Safeguards Order vacated in part and remanded, California v. FCC, 39 F.3d 919 (9th Cir. 1994) (California III), cert. denied, 115 S.Ct. 1427 (1995) (referred to collectively as the Computer III proceeding); Filing and Review of Open Network Architecture Plans, 4 FCC Rcd 1 (1988) (BOC ONA Order), recon., 5 FCC Rcd 3084 (1990) (BOC ONA Reconsideration Order); 5 FCC Rcd 3103 (1990) (BOC ONA Amendment Order), erratum, 5 FCC Rcd 4045 (1990), pets. for review denied, California v. FCC, 4 F.3d 1505 (9th Cir. 1993), recon., 8 FCC Rcd 97 (1993) (BOC ONA Amendment Reconsideration Order); 6 FCC Rcd 7646 (1991) (BOC ONA Further Amendment Order); 8 FCC Rcd 2606 (1993) (BOC ONA Second Further Amendment Order), pet. for review denied, California v. FCC, 4 F.3d 1505 (9th Cir. 1993).--In the Matter of Computer III Remand Proceeding: Bell Operating Company Provision of Enhanced Services, CC Docket No. 95-20, CC Docket No. 98-10, Report and Order, ¶ 7 (March 10, 1999).
[10] Regulatory and Policy Problems Presented by the Interdependence of Computer and Communication Services and Facilities (Computer I), 28 FCC 2d 291 (1970) (Tentative Decision); 28 FCC 2d 267 (1971) (Final Decision), aff'd in part sub nom. GTE Service Corp. v. FCC, 474 F.2d 724 (2d Cir. 1973), decision on remand, 40 FCC 2d 293 (1973).
[11] Amendment of Section 64.702 of the Commission's Rules and Regulations (Computer II), 77 FCC 2d 384,475-486, && 233-60. (1980) (Computer II Final Decision), recon., 84 FCC 2d 50 (1980) (Computer II Reconsideration Order), further recon., 88 FCC 2d 512 (1981) (Computer II Further Reconsideration Order), affirmed sub nom. Computer and Communications Industry Ass'n v. FCC, 693 F.2d 198 (D.C. Cir. 1982), cert. denied, 461 U.S. 938 (1983).
[12] United States v. AT&T, 552 F. Supp. 131 (DDC 1982), affirmed sub nom. Maryland v. United States, 460 U.S. 1001 (1983).
[13] Policy and Rules Concerning the Furnishing of Customer Premises Equipment, Enhanced Services and Cellular Communications Equipment by the Bell Operating Companies, CC Docket No 83-115, Report and Order, 95 FCC 2d 1117, 1120, & 3 (1984) (BOC Separation Order), affirmed sub nom. Illinois Bell Telephone Co. v. FCC, 740 F.2d 465 (7th Cir. 1984), affirmed on recon., FCC 84-252, 49 Fed. Reg. 26056 (1984) (BOC Separation Reconsideration Order), affirmed sub nom. North American Telecommunications Ass'n v. FCC, 772 F.2d 1282 (7th Cir. 1985).
[14] Computer III Phase I Order, 104 FCC 2d at 964-965, && 3-6. We discussed in detail the history of the Computer III proceeding in the Computer III Further Remand Notice, 10 FCC Rcd at 8362-8369, && 3-10.
"The Modified Final Judgment ("MFJ") originally prohibited the BOCs from providing information services, providing interLATA services, or manufacturing and selling telecommunications equipment or manufacturing customer premises equipment. United States v. AT&T, 552 F.Supp. 131 (DDC 1982), aff'd sub nom. Maryland v. United States, 460 U.S. 1001 (1983), vacated sub nom. United States v. Western Elec. Co., slip op. CA 82-0192 (DDC Apr. 11, 1996). The theory behind this prohibition in the MFJ was that the BOCs could leverage their market power in the local market to impede competition in the interLATA services, manufacturing, and information services markets. The information services restriction was modified in 1987 to allow BOCs to provide voice messaging services and to transmit information services generated by others. SeeUnited States v. Western Elec. Co., 673 F.Supp. 525 (DDC 1987); United States v. Western Elec. Co., 714 F.Supp. 1 (DDC 1988); United States v. Western Elec. Co., 767 F.Supp. 308 (DDC 1991). In 1991, the restriction on BOC ownership of content-based information services was lifted. United States v. Western Elec. Co., 767 F.Supp. 308 (DDC 1991), stay vacated, United States v. Western Elec. Co., 1991-2 Trade Cases (CCH) & 69,610 (D.C.Cir. 1991)."AT&T - Consent Decree - Modified Final Judgment
The Modified Final Judgment
(the MFJ), the antitrust consent decree which compelled AT & T to divest
the BOCs, originally prohibited the BOCs from offering any "information
services," a class of services that apparently is similar to enhanced services.
United States v. AT & T, 552 F.Supp. 131 (DDC1982), aff'd sub nom.
Maryland v. United States, 460 U.S. 1001 (1983). On March 7, 1988, the
U.S. District Court for the District of Columbia that oversees the MFJ
(the MFJ Court) issued an order removing that restriction for certain types
of information services for which the BOCs subsequently filed CEI plans.
U.S. v. Western Electric Co., Inc., No. 82-0192 (DDC filed Mar. 7, 1988)
(March 7 Order).
-- In the Matter of Filing
and Review of Open Network Architecture Plans, CC Docket No. 88-2, Phase
I, MEMORANDUM OPINION AND ORDER ¶ 29 n 60 (December 22, 1988)
"For the reasons stated,
the Court will exempt from the information services restriction the transmission
of information generated by others in the manner and to the extent described
above." United States v. Western Elec. Co., 673 F.Supp. 535, 597 (DDC
1987), affirmed in parted, reversed in part, 900 F.2d 283 (DC Cir 1990),
cert denied MCI v. US, 498 U.S. 911 (1990).
B. Information Services
The proposed
decree prohibits the Operating Companies from providing information services,
an umbrella description of a variety of services including electronic publishing
and other enhanced uses of telecommunications. [237] This prohibition is
necessary for reasons similar to those justifying the restriction on interexchange
services, as well as for additional reasons not relevant to the interexchange
problem.
All information
services are provided directly via the telecommunications network. The
Operating Companies would therefore have the same incentives and the same
ability to discriminate against competing information service providers
that they would have with respect to competing interexchange carriers.
Here, too, the Operating Companies could discriminate by providing more
favorable access to the local network for their own information services
than to the information services provided by competitors, and here, too,
they would be able to subsidize the prices of their services with revenues
from the local exchange monopoly. [238]
There
is also the effect on the configuration of the local networks to consider.
Many of the competitive problems in the interexchange market resulted from
the fact that competition was introduced after AT & T had designed
the local networks to service only its own Long Lines department. If the
Operating Companies are excluded from the information services market,
they will have an incentive, as time goes on, to design their local networks
to accommodate the maximum number of information service providers, since
the greater the number of carriers the greater will be the Operating Companies'
earnings from access fees. Thus, competition will be encouraged from the
outset. If, however, the Operating Companies were permitted to provide
their own information services, their incentive would be the precise opposite:
it would be to design their local networks to discourage competitors, and
thus to thwart the development of a healthy, competitive market. [239]
The restriction
on the provision of information services by the Operating Companies has
been attacked on the ground that it will remove their incentive to upgrade
the local networks and will cause them to become technological backwaters.
[240] This claim underrates the role of the Operating Companies under the
proposed decree. These companies will carry traffic between the information
service providers and their subscribers; their networks will therefore
have to be capable of carrying these technologically advanced services;
and they will have a financial incentive to create this capability because
they will earn access charges for providing this service. [241]
For all
of these reasons, the imposition of this restriction is fully consistent
with the antitrust laws.
FN237. For a full discussion of the meaning of this term see Part VI supra.-- United States v. AT&T, 552 F.Supp. 131, 189-90 (DDC 1982), aff'd sub nom. Maryland v. United States, 460 U.S. 1001 (1983), vacated sub nom. United States v. Western Elec. Co., slip op. CA 82-0192 (DDC Apr. 11, 1996).
FN238. For similar reasons, the Court rejects the argument that the Operating Companies can most efficiently provide information services by taking advantage of various economies (such as using the same equipment for exchange telecommunications and for information services). It would be impossible to determine at any time whether the Operating Companies' advantages were due to inherent efficiencies, or to efficiencies created by structuring the network so as to hinder competition. The experience with AT & T's activities with regard to interexchange competition indicates that the latter is a possibility which would be difficult to detect or prevent.
FN239. The reasons underlying the ban on provision of electronic publishing services by AT & T provide further support for restricting the Operating Companies from this activity. See Part VI supra.
FN240. It cannot be claimed that this restriction will result in rate increases: the Operating Companies do not now provide such services on any large scale, and it is not at all clear that they would be a great source of profit to them in the future.
FN241. Entry of the Operating Companies into this market is not necessary to provide competition for AT & T. The large amount of interest generated by this growing industry indicates that there will be a number of competitors. See Part V(A) supra.
24. In 1974, the United States Department of Justice (DOJ) filed
an antitrust complaint against AT & T, alleging that AT & T had
monopolized, or attempted to monopolize, a number of markets for telecommunications
equipment and services in violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act. 62
In 1982, AT & T and DOJ settled the complaint by agreeing to the entry
of a consent decree, which, after some significant modifications were made,
was adopted by the United States District Court for the District of Columbia
as a Modification of Final Judgment (MFJ). 63 The MFJ
required AT & T to divest itself of its wholly- owned operating companies,
the BOCs, and most of the assets held by the BOCs. Pursuant to the MFJ,
AT & T filed a Plan of Reorganization, which the Court also approved,
that provided for this divestiture and the reorganization of the 22 BOCs
into seven regional holding companies. 64 As a result
of divestiture, which took place on January 1, 1984, AT & T no longer
provides local exchange service and, in some states, intra-LATA 65
toll service. It does, however, continue in its other major lines
of business. AT & T retained its CPE and enhanced services businesses
as well as its research, manufacturing, and inter-LATA toll facilities.
The BOCs, as owners of local exchange facilities, were prohibited from
manufacturing CPE or providing inter- LATA transmission services and were
subjected to general line-of-business restrictions that limit the services
and products they may provide.
25. The MFJ treated AT & T and the BOCs in different ways
with regard to the provision of "information services", which it defined
as follows:
The offering of a capability for generating, acquiring, storing,
transforming, processing, retrieving, utilizing, or making available information
which may be conveyed via telecommunications, except that such service
does not include any use of any such capability for the management, control
or operation of a telecommunications system or the management of a telecommunications
service. 66
With respect to AT & T, the MFJ considered two general classes
of information services: 1) "electronic publishing," in which AT
& T would control the content of transmitted information, and 2) data
processing and other computer- related services, which would involve no
AT & T control of content other than for transmission purposes. 67
The MFJ prohibited AT & T from engaging in electronic publishing for
a period of seven years from the date of entry of the decree. The
Court concluded that such a restriction is necessary to avoid potential
dangers to competition and First Amendment values. 68
However, the MFJ formally freed AT & T from the general restrictions
on its provision of data processing and other computer-related services
imposed by the 1956 Decree, 69 since the Court found that AT
& T's unrestricted entry into such markets would likely "benefit the
American consumer, American foreign trade, and national defense". 70
26. However, the MFJ prohibited the BOCs from providing any information
services. The Court found that such a prohibition would not only
guard against potential discrimination and cross-subsidization, but also
would motivate the BOCs to design their local networks to accommodate the
maximum number of information service providers. According to the
Court, if the BOCs were permitted to provide information services, they
would have incentives to design the local networks to discourage competition,
71
but with the prohibition in place, their incentives to increase their earnings
from network access fees will lead them to implement network designs that
encourage competitive entry into information services.
--In the Matters of: Amendment of Sections 64.702 of the Commission's
Rules and Regulations (Third Computer Inquiry); and Policy and Rules
Concerning Rates for Competitive Common Carrier Services and Facilities
Authorizations Thereof Communications Protocols under Section 64.702 of
the Commission's Rules and Regulations, CC Docket No. 85-229, Report and
Order (June 16, 1986)
277. While it has been argued by various parties that AT&T
is foreclosed from engaging in activities which are not regulated, it is
by no means clear that this is in fact so. We note that Section IV
of the decree describes permissible activities of Western Electric and
Section V describes the permissible business activities of AT&T and
all of its subsidiaries, except Western Electric and Western Electric's
subsidiaries. [FN117] Based on our reading of these sections we stated
in the Tentative Decision, at para. 142, our belief that excluding CPE
from tariff-type regulation would not foreclose Bell System participation
in the CPE market. We read Section IV of the decree as permitting
Western Electric to sell or lease any type of equipment to the general
public which it sells or leases to Bell System companies either for service
to others or for their own use. In addition, we perceived enhanced
services as being incidental to the provision of common carrier communications
services under Section V(g) of the decree. Nothing has been presented
to us in the course of this proceeding which would lead us to conclude
otherwise. Nothing in Section V(g) requires that the incidental service
be provided by the same entity which owns the underlying transmission facilities.
Indeed, we have found that the record supports our belief that both enhanced
services and CPE are within our subject matter jurisdiction although that
jurisdiction is of the 'reasonably ancillary' type rather than Title II
jurisdiction. As such, these services and equipment reasonably fall
within the 'incidental to common carrier communications' language of the
consent decree. We therefore affirm our earlier conclusions.
See Tentative Decision at paras. 135-148. But we do not believe it
necessary to rely upon this 'incidental' proviso to Section V of the decree.
That Section plainly permits AT&T to furnish 'common carrier communications
services' which are defined in Section II(i) as 'communications services
and facilities . . . the charges for which are subject to public regulation
under the Communications Act of 1934 . . .' (Emphasis added.) Section
II(i) does not require that the 'regulation' to which it refers take any
particular form other than that it be 'public' and that it be 'under the
Communications Act of 1934.' Both criteria are satisfied by the regulatory
regime which we impose in this decision. The obvious purpose of the
'regulation' requirement is to ensure, through the scrutiny of an independent
body, that AT&T neither destroys competition nor charges consumers
excessive prices. These purposes are fully achieved here, in our
view, without the necessity for strict, tariff-type regulation. Moreover,
we believe that these purposes can be more fully realized under the separation
structure and through the medium of competition than if AT&T were allowed
to offer enhanced services as part of its regulated common carrier offerings.
278. We do not believe that the reference to 'communications'
in the defined phrase 'common carrier communications services' was intended
to have any separate prohibitory function so long as the services and facilities
remain 'subject to' regulation under the Communications Act. If the
services and facilities are a proper regulatory subject of that Act in
the eyes of the expert agency charged with enforcing that Act, it should
make no difference to an antitrust court, inclined to avoid duplicating
or interfering with that agency's judgment, that some of the services 'subject
to' regulation may include a larger element of data processing than basic
transmission. So long as the service is not wholly data processing
and devoid of any communications elements, the Commission's jurisdiction
reaches it. GTE Service Corp. v. FCC, 474 F.2d 724 (2d Cir. 1973).
279. In coming to these conclusions we are guided by the
principles of consent decree construction. We understand that the
1956 AT&T consent decree is to be construed as one would a written
contract, such that any command of the decree must be found within its
four corners. See United States v. Armour & Co., 402 U.S. 673
(1971); United States v. ITT Continental Baking Co. 420 U.S. 223 (1975).
We have previously indicated that DOJ's reliance on the 'regulation' criterion
as a benchmark for permissible activity does not comport with actual practices
of the Bell System. [FN118] The courts have previously refused to
accept any 'strained construction' by the Government that is inconsistent
with the 'normal meaning' of the language used. United States v.
Atlantic Refining Co., 360 U.S. 19, 22-23 (1959). In effect, DOJ
would read 'tariff regulation' into Section II(i) of the decree in place
of 'public regulation,' the term actually employed. We believe our
interpretation is the more consistent with the learning of Armour and ITT
Continental. We believe our reading of the decree is similarly compatible
with fundamental antitrust principles--the laws under which the judgment
court took jurisdiction--which favor open entry. See Northern Pacific
Railway v. U.S., 356 U.S. 1, 4 (1958). Moreover, such principles
have increasingly gained critical significance in the communications regulatory
environment. See United States v. FCC, F.2d, slip op. at 73.
(D.C. Cir. No. 77-1249, Mar. 7, 1980). Further, we believe that the prohibition
in the consent decree should be narrowly construed, because an expansive
reading would be restrictive of a free economy. Cf. United States
v. McKesson & Robbins, 351 U.S. 305, 316 (1956). [FN119]
280. We recognize that companies of the Bell System are
faced with making corporate decisions in the presence of uncertainty.
We obviously cannot guarantee that the consent decree does not impose some
constraint on their activities in these areas. At the same time,
however, removal of the uncertainty rests primarily with AT&T, should
AT&T deem it necessary. As we perceive the situation, the choice
rests with AT&T either to seek clarification from the judgment court
as to the limits of permissible activity in these areas, or, weighing the
risks, to proceed with its marketing plans for various types of CPE and
enhanced services.
281. We believe that the purposes of both our regulatory
statute and the antitrust laws are furthered by our adoption of a regulatory
scheme requiring separation of basic telecommunication services and enhanced
ancillary services and equipment so that customers in both markets are
given the benefit of the best service and the lowest cost. It is
a regulatory scheme that is conducive to the fullest exploitation of this
county's telecommunications networks, and will best serve all segments
of society. Even though uncertainty may exist for the Bell System
under this structure due to the consent decree, we believe that the costs
to society in general would be too great were there to be regulation in
these areas. It would be far worse to subject CPE and enhanced services
to regulation. However, should a decision of the judgment court disagree
with our reading of the decree and foreclose AT&T from the provision
of enhanced services or CPE, we would feel compelled to reassess the situation
to ascertain whether any revision to decisions made here would be warranted
in light of our statutory mandate. See Geller v. FCC, 610 F.2d 973
(D.C. Cir. 1979).
--In re Amendment of Section 64.702 of the Commission's Rules and Regulations
(Second Computer Inquiry), Docket No. 20828, Final Decision, 77 FCC2d
384 (May 2, 1980) (Computer II Final Decision)
. . . communications services and facilities, other than message telegram service, the charges for which are subject to public regulation under the Communications Act of 1934, or any amendment thereof, or would be subject to such regulation thereunder if such service or facility were furnished in interstate commerce; and shall also include any communications service or facility, other than message telegram service, the charges for which are or became subject to regulation under existing or future laws of any state, territory, or the District of Columbia, but only in the jurisdiction or jurisdictions in which the charges for such service or facility are subject to regulation.One of the seven exemptions is stated in V(g), which exempts 'business or services incidental to the furnishing by AT&T or such subsidiaries of common carrier communications services.' Section IV of the decree describes the permissible business activities of Western Electric. Section IV(b) permits Western Electric to engage in any business 'of a character or type engaged in by Western or its subsidiaries for companies of the Bell System . . .' The decree contains a separate provision with respect to manufacturing activities. Section IV(A) of the decree enjoins Western Electric and AT&T from manufacturing any kind of equipment for sale or lease 'which is not of a type sold or leased or intended be sold or leased to Companies of the Bell System, for use in furnishing common carrier communications services, . . .'111
2 United States v. Western Electric Co., Inc., and American Telephone and Telegraph Company. (consent judgment). 13 RR 2143; 1956 Trade Cases 71,134 filed January 24, 1956, D.C.N.J. (See also Paragraph 43 herein.)--In The Matter Of Regulatory And Policy Problems Presented By The Interdependence Of Computer And Communication Services And Facilities, Docket No. 16979, Tentative Decision, ¶ 24 (April 3, 1970)
First, a major regulatory concern of the Commission was the appropriateness of a carrier utilizing part of its communications switching plant of offer a data processing service. Further, there was the issue of whether communication common carriers should be permitted to sell data processing services and, if so, what safeguards should be imposed to insure that the carriers would not engage in anti-competitive or discriminatory practices. There was also concern as to the extent to which data processing organizations should be permitted to sell communications as part of a data processing package not subject to regulation.Purpose / Concerns
9. In our Tentative
Decision, we identified specifically the following areas of regulatory
concern:
(a) That the sale
of data processing services by carriers should not adversely affect the
provision of efficient and economic common carrier services;
(b) That the costs
related to the furnishing of such data processing services should not be
passed on, directly or indirectly, to the users of common carrier services;
(c) That revenues
derived from common carrier services should not be used to subsidize any
data processing services; and
(d) That the furnishing
of such data processing services by carriers should not inhibit free and
fair competition between communication common carriers and data processing
companies or otherwise involve practices contrary to the policies and prohibitions
of the anti-trust laws. (Tentative Decision, para. 34).
--In The Matter Of Regulatory
And Policy Problems Presented By The Interdependence Of Computer And Communication
Services And Facilities, Docket No. 16979, Final Decision and Order, ¶
9 (March 18, 1971) (Computer I).
24. We turn now to the problems posed by the provision of data processing services by common carriers. We have already concluded that so long as the data processing industry continues to retain its present competitive structure, such services should not be subject to common carrier regulation. This conclusion has a significant impact on the major common carrier, the American Telephone and Telegraph present competitive structure, such services should not be subject to a consent judgment which, with exceptions not applicable hereto, prohibits AT&T and its affiliated companies from engaging in any business other than the furnishing of regulated common carrier services. [FN2] It follows then that these companies cannot furnish data processing services. Other than this we know of no provision of law which prohibits or bars any other non-regulated service subject to certain safeguards. [FN3] To the contrary, our rules contemplate that other services may be furnished by such carriers and prescribe the methods of accounting for the reporting with respect to such services. [FN4]Dangers
38. It was prior to the development of these very different legal, technological and market circumstances that the Commission initiated its Computer Inquiry line of cases. In Computer I, the Commission addressed the questions of whether data processing services should be subject to regulation under Title II of the Act, and whether, and under what conditions, all common carriers should be permitted to compete in the market for data processing services. Finding that the computer data services industry "is one characterized by open competition and relatively free entry," the Commission concluded that it "should not, at this point, assert regulatory authority over data processing as such." Moreover, the Commission found that allowing common carriers to provide computer data services would likely benefit the public through "new and improved services and lower prices." Yet the Commission also recognized that common carriers might be able to "favor their own data processing activities by discriminatory services, cross-subsidization, improper pricing of common carrier services, and related anticompetitive practices and activities." Thus, the Commission required common carriers to furnish data processing services through a separate corporate entity that could not use regulated communications facilities to provide unregulated services. Finally, the Commission prohibited common carriers from discriminating in favor of their data processing affiliates.Reasons to Permit Carrier Offering of Enhanced Services
18. As to the issue of carrier participation, we recognized that provision of data processing services by common carriers might give rise to certain regulatory problems. Primarily, we were concerned with the possibility that common carriers might favor their own data processing activities through cross-subsidization, improper pricing of common carrier services, and related anti-competitive practices which could result in burdening or impairing the carrier's provision of its other regulated services. We therefore adopted a policy of 'maximum separation' whereby a communications common carrier had to furnish data processing services through a separate corporate entity. 2Maximum Separation / Structural Separation
Goals, Objectives
2 47 C.F.R. ss 64.702(c) and (d) require that a carrier establish a separate data processing entity having separate books of accounts, separate officers, separate operating personnel and separate equipment and facilities devoted exclusively to rendition of data processing services; and the carrier is prohibited from promoting the data processing services offered by the separate subsidiary. Carriers with annual revenue less than one million dollars were exempt from the maximum separation requirement.--Final Decision, In re Amendment of Section 64.702 of the Commission's Rules and Regulations (Second Computer Inquiry), 77 FCC2d 384, ¶ 18 (1980)
. . . assure (a) that such services will not adversely affect the provision of efficient and economic common carrier services; (b) that the costs related to the furnishing of such services will not be passed on directly or indirectly, to the users of common carrier services; (c) that revenues derived from common carrier services will not be used to subsidize any data processing services; and (d) that the furnishing of such services will not inhibit free and fair competition between communication common carriers and data processing companies or otherwise involve practices contrary to the policies and prohibitions of the antitrust laws. Tentative Decision at para 34.In adopting this policy, however, we made clear that
. . . we are not seeking to regulate data processing as such, nor are we attempting to regulate the substance of any carrier's offerings of data processing. Rather we are limiting regulation to requirements respecting the framework in which a carrier may publicly offer particular non-regulated services, the nature and characteristics of which require separation before predictable abuses are given opportunity to arise. Final Decision at para 30.125. The objectives of the maximum separation policy are still valid today. Carriers should not be permitted to burden their regulated communication services with costs properly allocable to their unregulated ventures to the detriment of users of communications common carriage facilities; nor should carriers be able to impose on the users of common carrier services the risks of loss that attend ventures in competitive areas, or sacrifice quality or efficiency in their regulated services. However, the specific rules which implement these objectives were formulated based on the market applications of computer technology prevalent at that time. With the advent of distributed processing the present rules may well inhibit the flexibility and availability of services designed to meet the unique communications needs of particular users or a class of users. This situation can be remedied by addressing in a different manner the concerns which gave rise to the need for a complete separation between a carrier's regulated and unregulated activities.
11. We turn now to the questions which have been raised as to the manner in which this concept should be implemented. Several parties have urged an outright prohibition against the furnishing of computer services by any communications common carrier, any affiliate of such a carrier, or any entity under common ownership with a carrier. Such a sanction would be extreme. It would be contrary to our policy of permitting the common carrier, directly or through affiliates, to engage in non-regulated activities so long as such activities are not repugnant to or in derogation of the economic and social objectives of the Act. (See Tentative Decision, para. 24). Furthermore, as we found in our Tentative Decision, the computer service industry is one characterized by open competition and relatively free entry. (See para. 19-23). These characteristics, in fact, provide a major basis for our conclusion that we should not, at this point, assert regulatory authority over data processing, as such. Under these circumstances, and in view of our expectation that the competition afforded by carriers in the provision of computer services could and would provide benefits in such matters as new and improved services and lower prices, we cannot find the necessary social, economic or policy consideration which would require or even justify an outright prohibition against the furnishing of data processing services by common carriers. We shall, therefore, reaffirm our Tentative Decision in its respect and permit the data processing industry to evolve with carrier participation therein under conditions designed to obviate foreseeable abuses. At the same time, we stress our intention to reconsider this conclusion should future experience indicate that any of the premises underlying this conclusion have not materialized or that in spite of our prescribed safeguards carrier abuses are developing.Outright Prohibition
16. In order to implement our concept of 'maximum separation', we have sought to establish requisites affecting the mode of operation of common carriers and their data processing affiliates. (See Tentative Decision, para. 36; Section 64.702 of the Commission's Rules, 47 C.F.R. 64.702, as proposed). Several carriers contend that the extent of separation we would require therein is 'unfair' and, if adopted as formulated, would place carrier data processors at a competitive disadvantage as compared to counterparts not affiliated with common carriers. We find this contention without merit. As we stated in our Tentative Decision:Competitive Disadvantage
For a relatively small capital investment, a service firm can be formed, computer equipment can be leased, and programmers can be hired. The factors which mark the difference between service bureau success or failure are imaginative innovation, quality programming, and useful service features, rather than the size of the staff or the computing installation. (para. 21).Consequently, we believe that our restrictions herein respecting corporate arrangements are neither onerous nor burdensome but reflect, rather, the market conditions confronted by those 800 or more noncarrier-related firms with whom
38. It was prior to the development of these very different legal, technological and market circumstances that the Commission initiated its Computer Inquiry line of cases. In Computer I, the Commission addressed the questions of whether data processing services should be subject to regulation under Title II of the Act, and whether, and under what conditions, all common carriers should be permitted to compete in the market for data processing services. Finding that the computer data services industry "is one characterized by open competition and relatively free entry," the Commission concluded that it "should not, at this point, assert regulatory authority over data processing as such." Moreover, the Commission found that allowing common carriers to provide computer data services would likely benefit the public through "new and improved services and lower prices." Yet the Commission also recognized that common carriers might be able to "favor their own data processing activities by discriminatory services, cross-subsidization, improper pricing of common carrier services, and related anticompetitive practices and activities." Thus, the Commission required common carriers to furnish data processing services through a separate corporate entity that could not use regulated communications facilities to provide unregulated services. Finally, the Commission prohibited common carriers from discriminating in favor of their data processing affiliates.Maximum Separation (Computer I) (All Carriers)
12. Having determined not to impose outright prohibitions against carrier provision of data processing services, we now turn to a consideration of the questions raised regarding those safeguards we have proposed in order to obviate any derogation of carrier communication service obligations to the public, or to prevent any abuse or limitation with respect to free competition because of the carrier's access to customers as a provider of communication services. As we stated in our Tentative Decision:
The dangers... relate primarily to the alleged ability of common carriers to favor their own data processing activities by discriminatory services, cross- subsidization, improper pricing of common carrier services, and related anticompetitive practices and activities. (para. 22).We proposed that common carriers desiring to provide data processing services be permitted to do so only through affiliates utilizing separate books of account, separate officers, separate operating personnel and separate equipment and facilities devoted exclusively to the rendition of data processing services.
The FCC determined that only "maximum separation" could prevent common carriers from engaging in cross subsidization, predatory pricing, and unfair competition. The FCC determined that it was only necessary to apply this maximum separation policy to common carriers earning over one million dollars a year, but only the American Telephone & Telegraph Co. (AT&T) fell into this category. However, such line drawing was irrelevant since AT&T and the Bell Operating Companies (BOCs) were already prohibited from providing competitive, non-common carrier services under a 1956 consent decree (Consent Decree).Minimum Threshold
36. Accordingly, we are hereby adopting
a policy that communications common carriers shall furnish data processing
services only through separate corporate entities. This requirement shall
be applicable to all communications common carriers engaged in interstate
or foreign communications services, including connecting carriers within
the meaning of Section 2(b)(2)(3) and (4) of the Communications Act, where
any such carrier itself has annual operating revenues exceeding $1,000,000
or any such carrier is directly or indirectly controlled by or is under
common control with another carrier or carriers and the combined annual
operating revenues of all such carriers exceed $1,000,000.5
Each such data processing entity shall be staffed with separate officers
and operating personnel and shall use equipment and facilities devoted
exclusively to the rendition of data processing and other non-common carrier
services. We shall also require that the data processing affiliate maintain
its own books of account and file with the Commission separate annual and
other reports as may be prescribed by the Commission pursuant to Section
218 of the Communications Act. Further, we shall require the submission
by the carrier (whether the carrier be a parent or subsidiary) of all inter-corporate
agreements and memoranda of any arrangements between the carrier and its
affiliate. When such separate corporate entity obtains communications facilities
or services from its affiliated common carrier, (whether parent or subsidiary)
it will be required to do so pursuant to the same tariff terms, conditions,
and practices as are applicable to any other customer of the carrier, and
specifically, on terms and conditions no more favorable than those offered
to other unaffiliated entities. Moreover, we shall require that no carrier
subject to the aforementioned conditions engage in the sale or promotion
of data processing activities on behalf of its data processing affiliate.
Finally, we will expect any affiliate of a common carrier to permit reasonable
interconnection with facilities of the customer.
--In re Regulatory And Policy Problems
Presented By The Interdependence Of Computer And Communication Services
And Facilities, Docket No. 16979, Tentative Decision, ¶ 36 (April
3, 1970)
41. We have reviewed the arguments of the international carriers who seek to provide data processing services that they be treated differently from domestic common carriers. There is no doubt that many of the potential abuses we foresee relate primarily to domestic carriers. However, there is a substantial potential for impact upon the communication services of the international carriers particularly in view of the rapid growth of both communication and data processing services. In addition, the international carriers maintain direct relations with many large users who could become data processing customers and are, therefore, in a position to affect adversely the free and unfettered competitive atmosphere in the provision of such services. We shall, therefore, affirm our conclusion that international carriers be fully subjected to this Decision and the Rules we are adopting.International Carriers
40. We turn now to the question respecting data processing services that the Bell System Companies perform for themselves and for independent telephone companies in connection with inter-carrier arrangements and traffic. In view of Bell's and the independent's position in oral argument, and the fact that there was voiced no opposition to such arrangements, we find that no need presently exists to interrupt this practice. We hasten to add that the above decision is premised, in part, upon the understanding that charges to the independent telephone companies for these data processing services are designed to and are fixed at levels sufficient to compensate only for actual costs. Accordingly, so long as the data services performed by the Bell System Companies are incidental to the inter-carrier provision of communication services, and so long as costs associated therewith are shared proportionately by the participating carriers, such practices may be continued.Carrier's Computers
13. Western Union contends
that certain economies and consequential public benefits would flow from
the public sale, lease or other disposition of a common carrier's 'off-peak'
or 'back-up' computing system capacity. While it may be true that costs
allocated to the sale of such capacity would reduce the revenues required
from communications services, we believe that the potential abuses inherent
in operations of this nature outweigh whatever benefits might be achieved.
First of all, a carrier's 'back-up' system should be designed to meet foreseeable
breakdowns of equipment dedicated to public service and it should be available
instantly for that purpose without the conflicting claims of other users.
With respect to 'off-peak' capacity, it is clear, assuming sound systems
analyses were employed by carrier personnel, that such capacity exists
only during those hours when the communications flow is light, and that
during peak hours, the systems' capacity approaches full utilization for
communication services provision. It is characteristic of common carrier
service that normal peaks shift and that abnormal or non-recurring peaks
eventuate from time to time. The use of 'off-peak' capacity for data processing
would derogate from the carrier's ability to accommodate these occurrences.
Such arrangements could result in an unacceptable conflict with the vital
public functions for which the carriers are licensed.
14. Aside from these
considerations, there are also other problems inherent in joint use of
facilities or personnel. Our experiences with attempting to allocate investment
and costs between and among communication services provided by fungible
plant and operated by the same personnel of a common carrier convince us
of the great difficulties which could be involved in allocation procedures
between communications and data processing activities. The potential for
abuse and the difficulty of preventing or promptly remedying improprieties
convince us that we should not alter our tentative conclusions as to the
desirability of the type of separation contemplated by or Tentative Decision.
15. Under these circumstances,
any economic benefits that might accrue to the carrier or its customers
by permitting the commingling of regulated and data processing activities
are, in our judgment, more than offset by the potential adverse effects
of such an arrangement. We conclude that a carrier's computer system or
systems should be dedicated exclusively to its public communication services
or to its 'inhouse' data processing requirements incidental thereto.
--In The Matter
Of Regulatory And Policy Problems Presented By The Interdependence Of Computer
And Communication Services And Facilities, Docket No. 16979, Final Decision
and Order, ¶ 11 (March 18, 1971) (Computer I).
18. We further stated in our Tentative Decision that no carrier subject to our proposed rules shall be permitted to 'engage in the sale or promotion of data processing activities on behalf of its data processing affiliate.' (Para. 36; Section 64.702(b)(3) of the Commission's Rules, 47 C.F.R. 64.702(b)(3)), as proposed. We consider such restriction consonant with our regulatory scheme of maximum separation. Several parties have indicated that, implicit in such restriction, is an extension which would prohibit the data affiliate from using the corporate name of the common carrier in its promotional activities. It is further urged that the carrier data affiliate should have a different name from the common carrier. It is argued, in essence, that if the above practices are not proscribed by Commission rule, the same coercive effect as with the carrier's solicitation of sales can be attained indirectly. Upon consideration of these contentions, we have decided to modify our rules to prohibit a data affiliate from using the name of its related common carrier in its promotions and, further, to prohibit such affiliate from using, in its corporate name, any words or symbols contained in the name of its affiliated carrier. [FN6] We recognize that, as a practical business matter, such improper promotions may occur in personal dealings between a data affiliate and its prospective customer. However, we admonish that we shall retain continuing jurisdiction over this matter and shall react appropriately if circumstances indicate that such wrongful promotional activity is taking place. Accordingly, we shall direct our rule against the use of name and symbols of the carrier affiliate toward any holding company owning or jointly owning a common carrier and a data processing entity, and toward any common carrier with an interest, direct or indirect, in a data processing affiliate.Cross Promotion
19. It has urged by several parties to this proceeding that the safeguards be extended to include a proviso that would prohibit a common carrier from obtaining that services of its data processing affiliate. It is contended that such arrangements between a carrier and its affiliate would be conducive to the development of the very substantive ills that our concept of maximum separation is designed to inhibit or, at least, to minimize. That is, such arrangements could result in the subsidization of the data processing affiliate, with the carrier's communications customers eventually absorbing the cost of inflated data processing charges through an extended rate base. Furthermore, it is urged that exclusive transactions between a carrier and its affiliate for data processing services would substantially impact the competitive market in which hundreds of small competing service bureau firms would be unable to obtain and retain the patronage of so significant a data processing customer. Additionally, it is contended, a significant burden would be placed upon the Commission to police the propriety of arrangements between a carrier and its data processing affiliate. Any improprieties in such dealings would be difficult to detect and rectify in view of the fact that data processing service offerings, and the charges made therefor, are neither fixed nor stable, but may vary considerably among customers.Services to Carriers by Affiliate
42. It has been pointed out that the Tentative Decision requires that carrier data affiliates file reports with us, that carrier data affiliates obtain communication services and facilities under tariff rates and conditions, and that carrier data affiliates offer reasonable customer interconnection options; but that none of these measures are to be made a requirement of our rules. See Tentative Decision, para. 36. With respect to the filing of affiliate reports, we are of the opinion that, at this time, except as provided in paragraph 36 supra and Section 64.702(f) of our Rules, it would be premature to prescribe rules requiring such separate affiliate reports. We feel that we should first observe developments under our policy and rules herein before addressing ourselves further to the question of what annual or other reports, if any, may be necessary from a carrier data affiliate in order to enable us to perform our statutory duties. With respect to tariff dealings between a carrier and its affiliate, we find no need to regulate such dealings by additional rule. For under the Communications Act and existing Commission Rules, a carrier data affiliate which leases communication facilities from its affiliated carrier is to be treated on the same basis as any non-affiliated lease of like or similar communication services. Should any carrier discriminate in favor of its data affiliate, this Commission possesses extensive authority under Title II of the Act to remedy the situation. Finally, with respect to the expectation of reasonable customer interconnection options, we are of the opinion that the keen competitive forces of the market place will best resolve this problem. It appears to us that if any data processor, carrier affiliated or otherwise, refuses to interconnect a device or system at the reasonable request of the customer, the latter can obtain relief by subscribing to a like service from a more competitive data offeror. If, however, our expectation is not borne out by actual developments and serious problems result from a refusal on the part of carrier data affiliates to permit reasonable interconnection or the attachment of customer devices to their data processing networks, we shall re-examine our position herein, including our present conclusion respecting the exercise of jurisdiction over data processing (See para. 4, supra).Service to Affiliate from Carrier
21. One of the more difficult policy problems we must further address in this proceeding concerns the circumstances in which a common carrier is the supplier of communication facilities and services to a competitor of its data processing affiliate. As we stated in our Tentative Decision:Discrimination
We expect that under no circumstances will carriers give any preferential treatment to their data processing affiliates and that carriers will scrupulously administer the terms and conditions of tariffs in making their facilities and services available to affiliates and non-affiliates on a non- discriminatory and non-preferential basis. (Tentative Decision, par. 37.)It has been suggested that both motive and opportunity are present in the above situation for a carrier to render favorable treatment to its affiliate to the expense of the latter's competitors. We are aware that such preferences may be suitable in nature and may include, among others, the provision of superior equipment, installation and maintenance, as well as more timely response to
27. On the other hand, we are prepared to render ad hoc evaluations with respect to 'hybrid services' to determine whether a particular package service offering is essentially data processing or communication. [FN9] We have decided upon this particular course of regulation because our analyses disclose that we have insufficient experience with such offerings to enable us to adopt rules of general applicability sufficiently definitive to accommodate the variety of further service offerings. We recognize that such offerings may be devised which present problems we cannot reasonably foresee, or which may be so specialized or variant in nature as to be impossible of capturing within the boundaries of a single rule. In these situations we believe we must retain power to deal with these offerings and the problems presented thereby on a case-by-case basis if our process is to remain flexible and effective. (See SEC v. Chenery Corp., supra, at 202-203).Hybrid Service
31. It is contended by several parties in this proceeding that this Commission is obligated by statute to regulate the 'hybrid service', as defined, [FN11] insofar as such service contains a communication component. We cannot agree. As we have indicated in our Tentative Decision:
It is our position that where message-switching is offered as an integral part of and as an incidental feature of a package offering that is primarily data processing, there will be total regulatory forebearance with respect to the entire service whether offered by a common carrier or non-common carrier... (Emphasis added). (Tentative Decision, para. 41).We believe that we are granted discretionary latitude, under the Communications Act and relevant judicial interpretations hereof, to refrain from subjecting a marginal activity to our regulatory process where it is clear that the public interest will be served by such a course. (See para. 28, supra.)In this instance, we believe that the imposition of regulatory constraints over what is clearly a data processing hybrid offering, even though it contains communications elements which are an integral part of and an incidental feature thereof, would tend to inhibit flexibility in the development and dissemination of such valuable offerings and thus would be contrary to the public interest. In essence, we recognize no overriding public interest requirement at this time to regulate a service which, due to its nature, except for incidental and peripheral communication elements, is appropriately offered in the existing competitive environment.
39. We turn now to those offerings of service which combine
data processing and message-switching to form a single integrated service
we have defined hereinbefore as a hybrid service. We have already made
it clear that it is not our intention to assert direct regulatory jurisdiction
over the sale of data processing whether engaged in either by conventional
communication common carriers or other entities despite the employment
of communications facilities to accomplish the data processing.When, however,
data processing is combined with message-switching, a different question
is presented. This is because message-switching is, in essence, an operation
which is inherent in the process of transmitting, by wire or radio, intelligence
of data from point of origin to point of destination. As in the case of
remote access data processing, user terminals are linked to the central
computer by communications channels. Thus, it is possible for users not
only to have on-line communication with the computer for data processing
purposes, but it is also possible for such users to have the means of communicating
with each other when the computer is programmed to switch messages of one
to another. Unlike data processing, however, the computer, when and if
used for message-switching, does not alter the content of the intelligence
transmitted. It simply performs the function of storage and either immediate
or delayed forwarding of the message to its addressed destination. In this
respect the computer takes the place of the manual or electro-mechanical
switching or relay operations which are typically involved in the transmission
of intelligence for hire by communications common carriers.
40. The specific question presented is, under what
circumstances should a message-switching capability, when offered in combination
with data processing services, be treated as a sale of communication for
hire subject to regulation under the Communications Act as are other communications
services offered for hire by common carriers? There is no pat formula which
provides the answer to this question because of the wide range of service
arrangements that are possible and actually obtain. However, we believe
that we can state certain general principles that will apply in the determination
of these questions in particular cases.
41. It is our position that where message-switching
is offered as an integral part of and as an incidental feature of a package
offering that is primarily data processing, there will be total regulatory
forebearance with respect to the entire service whether offered by common
carrier or non-common carrier, except to the extent that common carriers
offering such a hybrid service will do so through affiliates and will be
subject to regulatory safeguards as discussed above.
42. If, on the other hand, the package offering
is oriented essentially to satisfy the communications or message-switching
requirements of the subscriber, and the data processing feature or function
is an integral part of and incidental to message-switching, the entire
service will be treated as a communications service for hire, whether offered
by a common carrier or non- common carrier and will be subject to regulation
under the Communications Act. One applicable test will be whether the service,
by virtue of its message- switching capability, has the attributes of the
point-to-point services offered by conventional communications common carriers
and is, basically, a substitute therefor. Another test will be the extent
to which the message-switching feature of the service facilitates or is
related to the data processing component, or whether such message-switching
is essentially independent of such data processing. In effect, we shall
address ourselves to the facts surrounding a package offering with a view
toward determining the primary thrust of the service offered.
43. We deem it important that these distinctions
be carefully applied and that the essential nature of the service as primarily
data processing or communication not be artifically obscured. In the case
of AT&T and related Bell System companies, these distinctions are significant
since such companies are foreclosed by the AT&T Consent Judgment (supra)
from rendering non-tariffed services. Insofar as data processing is incidental
to communications within the meaning of Paragraph V(g) of the Consent Judgment,
as well as our policy statement herein, AT&T, and its affiliated operating
companies are free to furnish such a service. We intend to maintain a careful
and continuous observation of the activities of the Bell System companies
in their use and application of computer technology for both communications
and administrative purposes, to the end that such companies shall not offer
data processing which is not clearly incidental to communications within
the meaning of the Consent Judgment and this policy statement.
44. Similarly, in the case of Western Union, we
have already had occasion to consider the status of its SICOM and INFOCOM
services. We determined in 1967 that both of these services were common
carrier communications offerings in which computers were being used to
provide a transmission service that included the kind of message-switching
function traditionally performed by communications common carriers, as
well as other functions directly related to switching, such as error checking,
format control, and the like (In the Matter of SICOM, supra, at 9-12).
We stated further that if the services were broadened to include an offer
to perform data processing services other than the aforementioned message-switching
or related functions, the tariffs might be subject to rejection as offering
non-common carrier, non-communications services (In the Matter of SICOM,
supra, at 12). Under our decision herein, Western Union would be permitted
to continue to offer these services as tariffed common carrier communications
services. However, we shall expect any changes in the SICOM or INFOCOM
services to be reflected in appropriate tariff revisions which shall thereupon
be closely scrutinized by the Commission in order to determine whether
the modifications have altered the status of these services under the Communications
Act. If our examination reveals services of primarily data processing,
we would require Western Union to withdraw its tariffs and provide such
revised offerings through a separate corporate entity under our safeguard
rules.
45. We have heretofore deferred action on the question
of whether certain computerized switching services for airlines offered
by two existing common carriers, RCA and ITT, should be covered by tariffs
filed with us. (See Letters from the Federal Communications Commission
to RCA Communications, Inc., and ITT World Communications, Inc., December
20, 1967 (FCC File No. 9510.)
Our decision herein would require tariffs for such
services to be filed since they are not hybrid offerings exempted from
regulation. However, if the switching services were broadened to include
substantially data processing, they would be treated by the Commission
in the same manner as would an altered SICOM or INFOCOM service.
--In The Matter Of Regulatory
And Policy Problems Presented By The Interdependence Of Computer And Communication
Services And Facilities, Docket No. 16979, Tentative Decision (April 3,
1970)
219. Moreover the monopoly rent that a company can extract from such bottleneck facilities is likely to bear some relation to the number of subscribers served. It is probable that many of the new information services that will be offered over telephone lines will incur developmental expenses that will require large customer bases. As we observed, many of them are likely to be national in scope. A telephone company serving a relatively small proportion of the nation's homes and businesses is perhaps less likely to pursue such activities independently. For the most part, long-term profitable entry into the enhanced services field will probably require penetration of the market on a national scale, and it is unlikely that such a national operation could be effectively subsidized from a small pool of monopoly revenues, or that it could gain any significant competitive advantage by restricting the access of its competitors to a very limited network of underlying facilities. The effectiveness of other regulatory tools available to this Commission and other authorities is also considerably improved when they are applied to smaller telephone carriers.Computer II Structural Separation
Not Small Telcos
40. In Computer II, while underscoring the continued need for safeguards, the Commission also recognized the costs to carriers associated with "maximum separation." The Commission acknowledged, in particular, the impact of such costs on smaller carriers, and the fact that small carriers with a limited network were unlikely to be able to "gain any significant competitive advantage by restricting the access of its competitors to a very limited network of underlying facilities." Based on these considerations, the Commission concluded that it should continue to impose full structural separation requirements only on those carriers having control over local exchange facilities and sufficient market power to engage in anticompetitive activity on a national scale, namely AT&T and GTE.Structural Separation (BOCs was ATT and GTE)
80Id. at 468, para. 219.--In Re Appropriate Framework for Broadband Access to the Internet over Wireline Facilities, CC Docket No. 02-33, CC Dockets Nos. 95-20, 98-10, NPRM (February 15, 2002) http://hraunfoss.fcc.gov/edocs_public/attachmatch/FCC-02-42A1.doc
81Id. at 469-70, 473-74, paras. 223-24 and n.228.
3. In 1980, the Commission issued
Computer II, which adopted a regulatory scheme with two categories of communications
services: basic and enhanced. Basic services, such as "plain old telephone
service" (POTS), are regulated as tariffed services under Title II of the
Communications Act. Enhanced services use the existing telephone network
to deliver services other than basic transmission, such as voice mail,
E-Mail, voice store-and-forward, fax store- and-forward, data processing,
and gateways to on-line databases.
4. In Computer II, the Commission
concluded that enhanced services should not be regulated under Title II
of the Communications Act. [FN7] The Commission established rules to govern
the provision of enhanced services, including a requirement that the then-integrated
Bell System establish separate subsidiaries for the provision of enhanced
services. [FN8] Following the divestiture of AT & T in 1984, [FN9]
the Commission extended the structural separation requirements of Computer
II to the BOCs. [FN10]
-- In The Matter Of Computer III Further
Remand Proceedings: Bell Operating Company Provision Of Enhanced Services,
CC Docket No. 95-20, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, ¶¶ 3-4 (February
21, 1995)
"The FCC has found that a BOC is eligible for relief from the structural
separation requirement of Computer II when: a) it becomes technically able
to offer each of its initial ONA access services to ESPs; b) its federal
tariffs for each of its initial ONA access services are in effect; and
Commission) it has filed state tariffs for each of its intrastate ONA access
tariffs . . . In June 1992, Bell Atlantic became the first RHCs to be grated
relief from the structural separation requirement." --Henry M. Rivera
and Laura Johnson, Patents, Copyrights, Trademarks and Literary Course
Handbook: Panel on Developments in Manufacturing and Information/Enhanced
Services, 352 PLI/Pat 27, 47 (Dec. 3-4, 1992).
14. Under the Computer II structural separation rules, the AT
& T separate subsidiary was prohibited from providing basic services
or owning any network or local distribution transmission facilities, while
its basic services affilates were prohibited from offering enhanced services
or CPE. Those rules also strictly limited the interactions of the
separate subsidiary with its basic services affiliates. 33
We required the separate subsidiary to obtain all transmission facilities
necessary for providing enhanced services under tariff. 34
We required it to elect separate officers; maintain separate books
of account; employ separate operating, installation, and maintenance
personnel; and perform its own marketing and advertising. We
further required it to deal with any affiliated manufacturing entity only
on an arms-length basis and to utilize separate computer facilities in
providing enhanced services. Moreover, the separate subsidiary was
required either to develop its own software or to contract with non-affiliates
for such software, except that it was permitted to obtain generic software
embedded within equipment that its affiliate sold off-the-shelf to any
interested purchaser (the Software Rule). AT & T subsequently
established AT & T Information Systems, Inc. (AT & T-IS) as its
separate subsidiary for enhanced services and CPE.
--In the Matters of: Amendment of Sections 64.702 of the Commission's
Rules and Regulations (Third Computer Inquiry); and Policy and Rules
Concerning Rates for Competitive Common Carrier Services and Facilities
Authorizations Thereof Communications Protocols under Section 64.702 of
the Commission's Rules and Regulations, CC Docket No. 85-229, Report and
Order (June 16, 1986)
"Basic transmission services would be regulated under Title II while
enhanced services would not. Carriers affiliated with the American Telephone
and Telegraph Co. (AT&T) and General Telephone and Electronics Corp.
(GTE) would be required to offer enhanced services through a separate subsidiary
on a resale basis such that underlying transmission facilities are obtained
pursuant to tariff. "
--In the Matter of Amendment of Section 64.702 of the Commission's
Rules and Regulations (Second Computer Inquiry), Docket No.
20828, MO&O, 79 FCC2d 953 ¶ 5 (July 22, 1980) (resolving
requests for partial stays of final decision)
229. The thrust of applying the resale
structure to AT&T and GTE is to establish a structure under which common
carrier transmission facilities are offered by them to all providers of
enhanced services (including their own enhanced subsidiary) on an equal
basis. Inherent in the resale structure is the fact that the separate
corporate entity may not construct, own, or operate its own transmission
facilities. In essence, the resale subsidiary must acquire all its
transmission capacity from an underlying carrier pursuant to tariff.
This means that the same transmission facilities or capacity provided the
subsidiary by the parent, must be made available to all enhanced service
providers under the same terms and conditions. Requiring the subsidiary
to acquire its transmission capacity from other sources pursuant to tariff
provides a structural constraint on the potential for abuse of the parent's
market power through controlling access to and use of the underlying transmission
facilities in a discriminatory and anticompetitive manner.
230. The separate subsidiary for enhanced
services and CPE also provides a structural mechanism for the separation
of these carriers' regulated and nonregulated activities, thereby lessening
the potential that the communications ratepayer will be subsidizing their
unregulated ventures. While we discuss below the relationship between
the subsidiary and affiliated entities, the subsidiary itself is not regulated.
Thus the subsidiary may not provide basic transmission services for to
do so would subject it to regulation and negate the structural separation
of regulated and non regulated activities.
--Final Decision, In re Amendment of Section 64.702 of the Commission's
Rules and Regulations (Second Computer Inquiry), 77 FCC2d 384, ¶
229 (1980)
The Commission was concerned, however, that carriers providing both basic telecommunications services and enhanced services could discriminate against competitive enhanced service providers that sought to purchase underlying transmission capacity from the carrier.8 It stated that enhanced services are dependent upon the common carrier offering of basic services and that a basic service is the "building block" upon which enhanced services are offered.9 The Commission said an essential thrust of Computer II was to provide a mechanism whereby non-discriminatory access can be had to basic transmission services by all enhanced service providers.10Purpose
8 Basic communications services are regulated under Title II of the Communications Act. Basic services, such as "plain old telephone services (POTS)," provide pure transmission capability over a communications path that is virtually transparent in terms of its interaction with customer-supplied information. Id. at 420.-- In re Policy And Rules Concering The Interstate, Interexchange Marketplace/Implementation Of Section 254(G) Of The Communications Act Of 1934, As Amended/In 1998 Biennial Review -- Review Of Customer Premises Equipment And Enhanced Services Unbundling Rules In the Interexchange, Exchange Access and Local Exchange Markets, CC Docket No. 98-183; CC Docket No. 96-61, Report and Order (March 31, 2001) <www.fcc.gov/Bureaus/Common_Carrier/Orders/2001/fcc01098.doc>.
9 Id. at 474-75, para. 231.
10 Id.
"the absence of traditional public utility regulation of enhanced services
offers the greatest potential for efficient utilization and full exploitation
of the interstate telecommunications network Significant public benefits
accrue to the Commission's regulatory process, providers of basic and enhanced
services, and consumers under this approach."
--Final Decision, In re Amendment of Section 64.702 of the Commission's
Rules and Regulations (Second Computer Inquiry), 77 FCC2d 384, ¶
7 (1980)
Following the divestiture of AT&T in 1984,8 the Commission extended the structural separation requirements of Computer II to the Bell Operating Companies (BOCs).9Application to AT&T (BOCs) and GTE
8. United States v. AT&T, 552 F.Supp. 131 (DDC 1982), affirmed sub nom. Maryland v. United States, 460 U.S. 1001 (1983).In re US West Communications, Inc., Petition for Computer III Waiver, Order, 11 FCC Rcd. 1195 para 2 (Nov 6, 1995)
9. Policy and Rules Concerning the Furnishing of Customer Premises Equipment, Enhanced Services and Cellular Communications Equipment by the Bell Operating Companies, CC Docket No 83-115, Report and Order, 95 FCC 2d 1117, 1120, para. 3 (1984) (BOC Separation Order), affirmed sub nom. Illinois Bell Telephone Co. v. FCC, 740 F.2d 465 (1984), affirmed on recon., FCC 84-252, 49 Fed. Reg. 26056 (1984) (BOC Separation Reconsideration Order), affirmed sub nom. North American Telecommunications Ass'n v. FCC, 772 F.2d 1282 (7th Cir. 1985).
12. Weighing the public interest benefits of our objectives
and the economic tradeoffs inherent in a separate subsidiary requirement,
we have determined that limited imposition of the requirement will best
serve the communications ratepayer and the public interest more generally.
There is little need to subject carriers to the resale structure if such
entities lack significant potential to cross-subsidize or to engage in
other anticompetitive conduct. We find that only AT&T and GTE
present a sufficiently substantial threat such that they should be required
to establish separate corporate entities for the provision of enhanced
services and customer-premises equipment. We will not require any
other underlying carrier to form separate entities for the provision of
these services and CPE. Accordingly, we are removing the maximum
separation requirements for all carriers except those under direct or common
control of AT&T or GTE. In reaching this conclusion we recognize
that a reasonable balance can be struck only following a weighing of all
appropriate circumstances bearing upon the risks that largely captive monopoly
ratepayers will be burdened by anti-competitive conduct on the one hand
and that opportunities for economic efficiencies redounding to their benefit
may be lost on the other. The locus of the balance changes with circumstances.
Because we have the flexibility under the Communications Act to adjust
the balance as circumstances change or additional evidence is brought to
light, we opt for a solution in which only AT&T and GT&E must form
separate subsidiaries to offer ENHANCED service or CPE. Similarly, in establishing
guidelines governing the relationship of the separated entities with their
affiliates, we opt for a pragmatic approach which we can adjust when and
if necessary.
. . . . .
215. In ascertaining which carriers should be subject to the
resale structure the decision must be based not only on a carrier's ability
to engage in anti- competitive activity but also on its resources.
The latter is relevant because we have no desire to foreclose entry into
the enhanced services and CPE markets by any carrier. Hence, we must
give due recognition to the ability of carriers to cover the costs of separation.
Such costs include not only the capital expenditures involved, but also
some increased risks associated with separation which would presumably
be greater for the small carrier. For these smaller carriers, separation
may also result in more limited access to capital markets. Another
important factor is that if separation does cause some economic inefficiency,
the measure of this inefficiency will decrease as the size of the firm
increases. This is so because greater size corresponds to greater
flexibility in effectuating the separation, thus permitting closer approximation
to an economically efficient outcome. [FN85]
. . . . .
218. To the extent that all firms offering enhanced
services and CPE are not yet marketing their services on a nationwide basis,
we believe this is largely a function of the infant yet promising nature
of these markets. Regional markets, centering around large urban industrial
cities where the large business users are located may currently be another
appropriate area in which competition for these services can be measured.
But here, too, we note that only AT&T and GTE appear to have significant
abilities and incentives to engage in anticompetitive conduct, since it
is in these areas where they control the local facilities. In contrast,
the rural telephone companies would be hard pressed to attempt to bankrupt
competitors in their local areas where such competitiors may flourish in
the major metropolitan areas, or throughout the nation generally. Again,
we believe that the unlikely prospects of their success will in turn diminish
their incentives to attempt predation, leaving the local ratepayer at much
less risk than those captive to AT&T and GTE local services.
. . . . .
220. The need, then, does not exist
to subject carriers to the resale structure if such entities lack the potential
to cross-subsidize or to engage in anticompetitive conduct to any significant
degree. We believe that with the changes taking place in the competitive
makeup of the communications industry our regulatory concerns which give
rise to the need for structural separation should be directed at monopoly
telephone companies exercising significant market power on a broad geographic
basis.
221. Non-telephone carriers do not have
the kind of market power we are concerned with here. Specialized
carriers, such as MCI and SPCC, lack local distribution facilities entirely,
and have no reservoir of monopoly ratepayers from which to extract the
excess profits necessary to cross- subsidize other services. Such
carriers would be in a position to deny access on only a limited number
of interexchange transmission systems. Any private advantages from
such conduct would be short-lived, as customers could readily avail themselves
of alternative suppliers. Domestic satellite carriers also have no
local distribution plant, and no ability to monopolize interexchange transmission
systems. They are in competition not only with terrestrial systems,
but also with each other, and thus, with the possible exception of their
video service offerings, their market power is limited. Similarly
Western Union does not possess local monopoly facilities which could be
employed to deny or reduce access to enhanced services competitors nor
does it generate profits or cash flow comparable to that of the larger
telephone holding companies which could be employed as a source of cross-subsidies.
Moreover, we would expect our recent PMS decision to result in a further
diminution of any capacity Western Union might possess to engage in anticompetitive
conduct on a substantial basis. [FN88]
222. Weighing the competitive changes
which have occurred in the communications sector since the First Computer
Inquiry, we do not believe that broad application of the resale structure
is necessary to satisfy the regulatory objectives set forth there. Moreover,
we have been able to monitor the development of new and innovative services,
and conclude that the potential for these services to reach a greater segment
of society would be substantially increased if we exercised restraint in
the exercise of our discretion in applying the resale structure.
Weighing these factors, and recognizing the risks involved, we find that
the separation requirement should be applied only to those telephone companies
having sufficient market power to engage in effective anti-competitive
activity on a national scale and which possess sufficient resources to
enter the competitive market through a separate subsidiary.
223. An objective standard upon which
a determination can be made as to which telephone companies possess these
characteristics is not easily established. However, when we examine Table
1, we see that only four companies have more than 1% of industry revenues,
and a fifth is above the 1% level in terms of number of telephones.
As the Table exhibits, there is a sharp distinction with respect to these
shares between AT&T and the rest of the industry and between GTE and
the rest of the independents. The companies ranked 3, 4 and 5 in
terms of revenues form an approximate group of their own. The remaining
companies possess a combination of size, geographic service area(s), and
monopoly revenue base (which is typically a small fraction of the total
operating revenues shown in Table 1) such that we are not convinced that
the benefits of separation outweigh the costs. Even when we consider
the market penetration of the top five carriers listed in Tabel 1, a fairly
clear distinction can be drawn between AT&T and GTE on the one hand,
and the other telephone companies on the other hand. Because of the
relative size of AT&T and GTE and the diverse national markets they
serve, we conclude that, at present, the resale structure should be applied
to AT&T and GTE. We realize that an argument could be made for
subjecting other telephone companies to this structure, but we conclude
that it would better serve the public interest to take a restrictive approach
at this juncture in applying the resale structure and wait to see if competitive
abuses develop which warrant further application of this structure for
either enhanced services or CPE.
. . . . .
227. The rationale for imposing a separation
requirement only on AT&T and GTE has even greater force when considering
CPE. Only these two U.S. telephone companies have basic manufacturing
operations producing large quantities of a wide range of telecommunications
equipment. Both AT&T and GTE hold substantial market positions,
if not market power, in the provision of certain kinds of CPE. Their
significant participation in these markets indicates that these companies
have substantial incentives to sustain their market positions by thwarting
the provision of such equipment on a competitive basis. Their local
monopoly positions, in turn, provide the opportunity (without maximum separation)
to engage in such anticompetitive conduct--with the monopoly ratepayer
being forced to subsidize below cost pricing of CPE. United and Continental,
on the other hand, have shown little inclination to participate in the
equipment manufacturing market, apparently due to the cyclical nature of
profits in that market. Continental Supply and Service Corporation
does provide centralized purchase and distribution of equipment and parts
for Continental's operating telephone companies, and Continental Telephone
Laboratories tests and recommends practical applications for equipment;
but the carrier sold its primary manufacturing subsidiary (Vidar Corporation)
in 1975, explaining to stockholders that '[T]he cyclical nature of manufacturing
operations and other considerations have led to the conclusion that the
Company and its stockholders would benefit by withdrawal from the field
of manufacturing and by concentration of investment and manpower in telephone
operations.' [FN96] The following year Continental completed its
divestiture of manufacturing operations with the sale of the Cable Division
of Superior Continental Corporation, and again cited the 'volatility of
earnings inherent in the cyclical nature of these operations.' [FN97]
Similarly, United's subsidiary, North Supply Company, an international
distributor of telecommunications products with more than a quarter of
a billion dollars in annual sales, was formerly a division of North Electric
Company. United sold the manufacturing division of North Electric
in 1977, incurring a $2.3-million loss on the transaction, and notified
stockholders that the sale, together with the 1978 sale of Central Kansas
Power Company, left 'United Telecom's resources concentrated in three activities--telephone
service, computer services and distribution services. All are strong
markets and United is well positioned in each of them.' [FN98]
228. Thus we believe that continued
application of our maximum separation policy to all carriers is inappropriate
in the face of the present and foreseeable market applications of computer
processing technology and increased competition in the provision of regulated
communications services. Contrary to the approach in the Tentative Decision,
we conclude that not all carriers owning transmission facilities should
be required to provide enhanced services through a separate corporate entity.
Separation is appropriate in those cases in which there is a substantial
threat of injury to the communications ratepayer and where other regulatory
tools would not suffice. Both AT&T and GTE provide franchised monopoly
telephone service and competitive services. Moreover, both are vertically
and horizontally integrated with affiliated equipment manufacturers which
supply the preponderant share of the equipment needs of the affiliated
telephone companies. Thus, both AT&T and GTE have significant
market positions in various equipment product lines as well as certain
service categories in certain large geographic markets. We are thus
concerned that both companies could exploit their dominance in these product
lines to support below cost prices in more competitive markets. Weighing
the public interest benefits of our objectives and the economic tradeoffs
of the separate subsidiary requirement, we have determined that restricting
the requirement to AT&T and GTE will best serve the monopoly and other
communications ratepayers and the public interest more generally.
Accordingly, we are removing the maximum separation requirements for all
carriers except those under direct or indirect common control of AT&T
or GTE.
--Final Decision, In re Amendment of Section 64.702 of the Commission's
Rules and Regulations (Second Computer Inquiry), 77 FCC2d 384, ¶¶
218, 220 (1980)
Web services provided by
|
: ADA : Broadband : Crime : Copyright : DNS : ECommerce : EGovt : First Amendment : Digital Divide : : Network Neutrality : Intl : Privacy : Security : SPAM : Statistics : VoIP : Vote : And Much More! : :: Feedback : Disclaimer :: |